翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ Cost segregation study
・ Cost sharing
・ Cost Sports Center
・ Cost the limit of price
・ Cost to company
・ Cost to serve
・ Cost, Texas
・ Cost-based anti-spam systems
・ Cost-effective minimum water network
・ Cost-effectiveness analysis
・ Cost-Effectiveness Analysis Registry
・ Cost-exchange ratio
・ Cost-loss model
・ Cost-minimization analysis
・ Cost-of-living index
Cost-of-production theory of value
・ Cost-plus contract
・ Cost-plus pricing
・ Cost-plus pricing with elasticity considerations
・ Cost-plus-incentive fee
・ Cost-push inflation
・ Cost-shifting
・ Cost-weighted activity index
・ Costa
・ Costa (coral)
・ Costa (surname)
・ Costa Andricopoulos
・ Costa Atlantica
・ Costa Azul
・ Costa Azul LNG


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

Cost-of-production theory of value : ウィキペディア英語版
Cost-of-production theory of value
In economics, the cost-of-production theory of value is the theory that the price of an object or condition is determined by the sum of the cost of the resources that went into making it. The cost can comprise any of the factors of production (including labor, capital, or land) and taxation.
The theory makes the most sense under assumptions of constant returns to scale and the existence of just one non-produced factor of production. These are the assumptions of the so-called non-substitution theorem . Under these assumptions, the long-run price of a commodity is equal to the sum of the cost of the inputs into that commodity, including interest charges.
==Historical development of theory==
Historically, the best-known proponent of such theories is probably Adam Smith. Piero Sraffa, in his introduction to the first volume of the "Collected Works of David Ricardo", referred to Smith's "adding-up" theory. Smith contrasted natural prices with market price. Smith theorized that market prices would tend toward natural prices, where outputs would stand at what he characterized as the "level of effectual demand". At this level, Smith's natural prices of commodities are the sum of the natural rates of wages, profits, and rent that must be paid for inputs into production. (Smith is ambiguous about whether rent is price determining or price determined. The latter view is the consensus of later classical economists, with the Ricardo-Malthus-West theory of rent.)
David Ricardo mixed this cost-of-production theory of prices with the labor theory of value, as that latter theory was understood by Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk and others. This is the theory that prices tend toward proportionality to the socially necessary labor embodied in a commodity. Ricardo sets this theory at the start of the first chapter of his "Principles of Political Economy and Taxation". He also refutes the labor theory of value in later sections of that chapter. This refutation leads to what later became known as the transformation problem. Karl Marx later takes up that theory in the first volume of ''Capital'', while indicating that he is quite aware that the theory is untrue at lower levels of abstraction. This has led to all sorts of arguments over what both David Ricardo and Karl Marx "really meant". Nevertheless, it seems undeniable that all the major classical economics and Marx explicitly rejected the labor theory of price〔Donald F. Gordon, "What was the Labor Theory of Value", ''American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings'', V. 49, n. 2 (May 1959): 462–472〕(()).
A somewhat different theory of cost-determined prices is provided by the "neo-Ricardian School" () of Piero Sraffa and his followers.
The Polish economist Michał Kalecki () distinguished between sectors with "cost-determined prices" (such as manufacturing and services) and those with "demand-determined prices" (such as agriculture and raw material extraction).

抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「Cost-of-production theory of value」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.